British credit crisis of 1772-1773
The British credit crisis of 1772-1773 also known as the crisis of 1772, or the panic of 1772, was a peacetime financial crisis which originated in London and then spread to Scotland and the Dutch Republic in December.[1] It has been described as the first modern banking crisis faced by the Bank of England.[2] New colonies, as Adam Smith observed, had an insatiable demand for capital. Accompanying the more tangible evidence of wealth creation was a rapid expansion of credit and banking leading to a rash of speculation and dubious financial innovation (venture capitalism). In today’s language, they bought shares on margin.[3] The credit boom came to an abrupt end, and the ensuing crisis harmed the East India Trading Company, the West Indies in general, and the North American colonial planters specifically.[4]
.jpg.webp)
In June 1772 Alexander Fordyce lost £300,000 shorting East India Company stock, leaving his partners liable for an estimated £243,000 in debts.[5] As this information became public 30 banks across Europe collapsed.[6][7][8] The boom and subsequent crisis were most pronounced in Scotland.[1] but also triggered a liquidity crunch in Amsterdam. In the end, none of them actually lost money.[3] According to Paul Kosmetatos existing literature dealing with aspects of the episode—no comprehensive coverage exists up to now.
Before the Crisis
_1.463_-_Dividend_Day_at_the_Bank%252C_1770.jpg.webp)
From the mid-1760s to the early 1770s, the credit boom, supported by merchants and bankers, facilitated the expansion of manufacturing, mining and internal improvements in both Britain and the thirteen colonies. Until the outbreak of the credit crisis, the period from 1770 to 1772 was considered prosperous and politically calm in both Britain and the American colonies. As the result of the Townshend Act and the breakdown of the Boston Non-importation agreement, the period was marked with a tremendous growth in exports from Britain to the American colonies. Exports to North America increased rapidly compared to imports to North America between 1750 and 1772. These massive exports were supported by credit that British merchants granted to American planters.[9] The Physiocrats believed in land development and agriculture.
Problems, however, lay behind the credit boom and the prosperity of both British and colonial economies: speculation and the establishment of dubious financial institutions. For example, in Scotland, bankers adopted "the notorious practice of drawing and redrawing fictitious bills of exchange…in an effort to expand credit".[1] For the purpose of increasing the supply of money, the bank of Douglas, Heron & Company, known as the "Ayr Bank", was established in Ayr, Scotland in 1769; however, after the original capital was exhausted, the firm raised money by a chain of bills on London.[1] Henry Hamilton has explained how a chain of bills works, "A, say in Edinburgh, drew a bill on his agent B in London, payable in two months. Before payment was due B redrew on A for the same sum plus interest and commission. Meantime A discounted his bill in Edinburgh and before the two months were up he drew another bill on B and so on".[10] This method could only temporarily support economic development, yet it promoted false optimism in the market. The warning signals of the impending crisis, such as the overstocked shelves and warehouses in the colonies, were completely overlooked by British merchants and American planters.[1]
Effects in London
_Macaroni._Gambler_(BM_1915%252C0313.151).jpg.webp)
In July 1770 Alexander Fordyce collaborated with two planters on Grenada and borrowed 240,000 guilders in bearer bonds from Hope & Co. in Amsterdam.[11][12][13] He was a partner in the banking house Neale, James, Fordyce and Down in Threadneedle Street (London), and correspondents of the (large) Ayr Bank.[14] He bet heavily against EIC share price, which went awfully awry.[15] Fordyce had speculated away the bank's assets. On Monday 8 June 1772, it became clear Fordyce failed.[16][17] The next day he fled to France to avoid debt repayment. He used the profits from other investments to cover the losses.[18] The initial distress in London peaked on 22 June (Black Monday).[19] The whole City was in uproar when Fordyce was declared bankrupt.[20] The experimental and ill-fated Ayr Bank (Douglas, Heron & Co.) followed on 24 June.[21][22] There was great uncertainty about the size of the shock.[23] Economic growth at that period was highly dependent on the use of credit, which was largely based upon people’s confidence in the banks. As confidence started ebbing, paralysis of the credit system followed: crowds of people (creditors) gathered at the banks and requested debt repayment in cash or attempted to withdraw their deposits. As a result, twenty important banking houses went bankrupt by the end of June, and many other firms endured hardships during the crisis.[24] At that time, the Gentleman's Magazine commented, "No event for 50 years past has been remembered to have given so fatal a blow both to trade and public credit".[25] The strain upon the reserves of the Bank of England was not eased until towards the end of 1773.
After the crisis, a dramatic rise in the number of bankruptcies was observed: the average number of bankruptcies in London was 310 from 1764 to 1771, but the number rose to 484 in 1772 and 556 in 1773.[1] Banks that were deeply involved in speculation endured hard times during the crisis. For example, the partners of the Ayr Bank paid no less than £663,397 in order to fully repay their creditors. Owing to this process, only 112 out of 226 partners remained solvent by August 1775. In contrast, banks that had never engaged in speculation did not bear any losses and gained prestige for their outstanding performance despite the turbulence.[10]
Effects in Scotland
- In 1769 the moneyed interests in Scotland founded the Ayr Bank to assume many of the responsibilities associated with a central bank, principally standing ready to advance notes to Scottish banks as a 'lender of last resort.'[26]
- Like other banks established in the form of limited liability companies, the Ayr Bank had the right to put banknotes into circulation, which power it used excessively.[27] By 1772, in addition to its headquarters in Ayr, the Ayr banking group had branches in Edinburgh and Dumfries, as well as representative offices in Glasgow, Inverness, Kelso, Montrose, Campbeltown, and several other places. Among the company's shareholders were well-known people such as the Duke of Buccleuch and Queensberry, the Earl of Dumfries, the Earl of March, Sir Adam Fergusson of Kilkerran, Patrick Heron of Heron, and the Honorable Archibald Douglas.[28]
- On 12 June the news of the failure of Neal, James, Fordyce and Down reached Scotland. After the weekend a run began on its Edinburgh branch.[29] The “Ayr” bank collapsed on 24 June, bringing other smaller banks down with it having extended credit too liberally to colonial planters.[30] The Ayr bank managed to reopen for a brief period between September 1772 and August 1773, but a general meeting of the partners held on 12 August decided to dissolve the Company permanently.
- The bank may have actually spurred the economic development of Scotland, but its failure weakened public confidence in land banking schemes, leaving gold and silver as the most acceptable security for bank notes.
In his History of Banking in Scotland Andrew William Kerr wrote:
The crisis of 1772, which formed the subject of our last chapter, although sharp and disastrous in its immediate effects, passed off more quickly and easily than might have been expected... The harvest of 1773 was fairly good, the fisheries excellent, the cattle trade active, and money cheap. Hardly had affairs resumed a satisfactory aspect, when the dark cloud of war cast its shadow over the land.[31]
- According to Adam Smith, in 1773 busy writing The Wealth of Nations: "Being the managers rather of other people's money than of their own, it cannot be well expected, that they should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which the partners in a private co-partnery frequently watch over their own."[32]
Effects on Europe

In December 1772 Clifford & Co went bankrupt which held plantation loans as part of its portfolio. The bearer bonds on Surinam dated from 1 October 1769. The plantation mortgages had many features in common with the subprime mortgages on American houses.[33][34] The negotiations set up by the Cliffords and Hope & Co in the Danish West Indies issued bonds to finance the loans. Such packages could contain loans to 20 or more plantations and before 1772 at least 40 of these bundles were issued, their names as unspecific as L.a. A, B or C. Investors thus had little knowledge of what they invested in, and lent their money purely on good faith and the word of the fund director. The Dutch fund managers, were also hit personally once their subprime system met its inevitable demise.[35] The credit crunch was a real disaster for the Dutch plantation colonies in the West Indies and particularly for Surinam, where colonial agriculture was almost exclusively carried out with credit from Amsterdam.[36] The Bank of Amsterdam funded a city-operated loan facility for distressed merchants.[37][38]
The cause of this failure, like Fordyce in London, was the over speculation of East India stock. This precipitated a string of further failures and a general state of crisis throughout Amsterdam- according to Wilson, ‘Conditions…were even worse than in 1763 … there was paper enough but no cash; hardly a man on the Bourse or in the bill business could produce 50,000 guilders; credit was non-existent, the circulation of money had stopped and so had the discount business; loans on bonds and goods were scarce, and only a little business was being done on foreign securities. Some houses stood seven to eight hundred guilders in debt.[39]
In Amsterdam a worse catastrophe was averted by rapid imports of precious metals.[28] In January 1773 Joshua Vanneck and his brother were involved (by Thomas Walpole) when British merchants sent ₤500,000, gold and piastre to Amsterdam.[40][41][42]
A few bankruptcies also shook the economies of Stockholm and St. Petersburg a little later, but overall Europe got off relatively lightly.[43][44] The Danish Kurantbanken was nationalized in March 1773 with the assistance of Heinrich Carl von Schimmelmann; the shareholders received the fixed interest bonds instead of shares on plantations in the Danish West Indies.[45][46] In April 1773 Pels & Sons, the second biggest bank in Amsterdam liquidated; Hope & Co. was already the leading banking house.[47] Although Hope & Co came through the crisis well, it suffered from the aftermath. The turnover with the Amsterdam Exchange Bank plummeted from more than 50 million guilders in 1772 to 30 million in 1773.[48]
East India Company
The East India Company, formerly mainly a trading company with a limited territory, was now entrusted with the management of a much larger area, for which task its outdated organisation was not up to. At the London Stock Exchange, however, there was still the expectation that the Company would soon be paying higher dividends, an expectation shared by the Dutch capital owners who were used to investing part of their capital in English funds. This optimism gave rise to increasing speculation boom in the futures trade in securities in both London and Amsterdam.[49]
In May 1772 the EIC stock price rose significantly. In summer the EIC's debt suddenly skyrocketed - in India alone, the company had bill debts of £1.2 million. Meanwhile, speculation in futures in East India stock had weakened the London money market. The Great Bengal famine of 1770, which was exacerbated by the actions of the East India Company, led to massive shortfalls in expected land values for the company. The East India Company bore heavy losses and its stock price fell significantly. Hope was stuck with a considerable positions in EIC and BoE stock. On 19 September the value of its shares dropped by 14%.[50]
The root of this crisis in relation to the East India Company came from the prediction by Isaac de Pinto that ‘peace conditions plus an abundance of money would push East Indian shares to ‘exorbitant heights.’[42] As leading Dutch banking houses (Andries Pels and Clifford & Son) had invested extensively in the stock of the East India Company, they suffered the loss along with the other shareholders. In this manner, the credit crisis spread from London to Amsterdam.[24][44]
The East India Company had eighteen million pounds of tea sitting in British warehouses. Selling it in a hurry would do wonders for its finances.[51] On 14 January 1773 the directors of the EIC asked for a government loan and unlimited access to the tea market in the American colonies, both of which were granted.[52] In August the Bank of England assisted the EIC with a loan.[53] The British Government passed the Tea Act in order to raise tax revenue, stabilize the economy, and help the East India Company’s recovery. The Tea Act proved to be wildly unpopular in the colonies, leading to the infamous Boston Tea Party… which was a major precursor to the American Revolution.[54]
Effects on the thirteen colonies
The credit crisis of 1772 greatly deteriorated debtor-creditor relations between the thirteen American colonies and Britain, especially in the South. The southern colonies, which produced tobacco, rice, and indigo and exported them to Britain, were granted higher credit than the northern colonies, where competitive commodities were produced. (It was estimated that in 1776 the total amount of debt that British merchants claimed from the colonies equaled £2,958,390; Southern colonies had claims of £2,482,763, nearly 85 per cent of the total amount.[55] Before the crisis, the commission system of trading prevailed in the southern plantation colonies. The merchants in London helped the planters sell their crops and shipped what planters wanted to purchase in London as returns. The commission equaled the price of the British goods minus the revenue of the crops. The planters were usually granted credit for twelve months without interest and at five per cent on the unpaid balance after the deadline.[1]
News of the crash in Scotland reached Thomas Jefferson in a letter dated 8 July 1772. After the outbreak of the crisis, British merchants urgently called for debt repayment, and American planters faced the serious problem of how to pay the debt for several reasons. First, because of the economic boom before the crisis, planters were not prepared for large-scale debt liquidation. As the credit system broke down, bills of exchange were rejected and almost all heavy gold was sent to Britain in December 1773. Second, without the support of credit, planters were unable to continue producing and selling their goods. Since the whole market became crippled, the fallen price of their goods also intensified the pressure on planters. Owing to the crisis, the colonies endured hard times to maintain the balance of payments.[1]
The Crisis of 1772 also set off a chain of events related to the controversy over the colonial tea market. The East India Company was one of the firms that suffered the hardest hits in the crisis. Failing to pay or renew its loan from the Bank of England, the firm sought to sell its eighteen million pounds of tea from its British warehouses to the American colonies. Back then the firm had to market its tea to the colonies through middlemen, so the high price made its tea unfavorable compared to the tea that was smuggled to, or was produced locally in, the colonies. In May 1773, however, the Parliament imposed a three pence tax for each pound of tea sold, and allowed the firm to sell directly through its own agents.[56] The Tea Act reduced the tea price and enabled the East India Company’s monopoly over the local tea business in the colonial tea market. Furious about how British government and the East India Company controlled the colonial tea trade, citizens in Charleston, Philadelphia, New York and Boston rejected the imported tea, and these protests eventually led to the Boston Tea Party in December 1773.[57] Bills of exchange had become so scarce by December 1773 that all of the dollars and heavy gold had been sent to Great Britain for remittance.[1] The crisis also worsened the relationship of the North American colonies and Britain, due to the fact that it affected all 13 of the colonies, and due to the fact that the British were forced to introduce controversial legislation for the colonies in an attempt to remedy the crisis, which made the crisis one of the causes of the American Revolutionary War.[57]
Further reading
- Geest, Patrick van der (2021) In Search of the First Domino: The Credit Crisis of 1772-1773 in a Global History Perspective
- Goodspeed, T. (2016) Legislating Instability
- Hoonhout, Bram (2013) The crisis of the subprime plantation mortgages in the Dutch West Indies, 1750-1775
- Kosmetatos, Paul (2018) Last resort lending before Henry Thornton? The Bank of England’s role in containing the 1763 and 1772–1773 British credit crises, European Review of Economic History.
- Koudijs, Peter and Hans-Joachim Voth (2011) Optimal delay: distressed trading in 18th c. Amsterdam
- Koudijs, Peter (2011) Trading and Financial Market Efficiency in Eighteenth Century Holland
- Narron, James and David Skeie (2014) Crisis Chronicles: The Credit and Commercial Crisis of 1772
- Rockoff, Huge (2009) UPON DAEDALIAN WINGS OF PAPER MONEY: ADAM SMITH AND THE CRISIS OF 1772
- Joanna Rudd () The International Lender of Last Resort- An Historical Perspective
Notes
- "The British Credit Crisis of 1772 and the American Colonies" The Journal of Economic History
- Rockoff, Hugh T., Upon Daedalian Wings of Paper Money: Adam Smith and the Crisis of 1772 (December 2009). NBER Working Paper No. w15594, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1525772
- https://www.gsb.stanford.edu/insights/peter-koudijs-risk-analysis-or-risk-paralysis
- https://www.fichansraj.org/post/how-credit-crisis-of-seventeenth-century-sparked-american-revolution
- Tyler Goodspeed: Legislating Instability: Adam Smith, Free Banking, and the Financial Crisis of 1772
- "The East India Company: The original corporate raiders | William Dalrymple". The Guardian. 4 March 2015. Retrieved 8 September 2020.
- "The Credit Crisis of 1772 - Recession Tips". 26 November 2021.
- A history of Banking in All the Leading Nations, p. 98
- "The American Credit Crisis (of 1772) Visualized | Doug McCune". 5 January 2010.
- "The Failure of the Ayr Bank, 1772" The Economic History Review
- Amsterdam City Archives on 3 July 1770, NA 5075, nr. 426
- Clapham, p. 249
- 'Henry Hope', Legacies of British Slavery database, http://wwwdepts-live.ucl.ac.uk/lbs/person/view/2146665491 [accessed 4th May 2022].
- Sheridan, p. 171
- Wilson, C. (1941/1966?), p. 120-121
- The papers of Henry Laurens, Band 8 by Henry Laurens
- http://www.ouramericanrevolution.org/index.cfm/page/view/m0177
- https://www.jamesboswell.info/biography/alexander-fordyce-macaroni-gambler
- Saville, Richard (1996). Bank of Scotland: A History, 1695-1995. ISBN 9780748607570. Retrieved 23 March 2013.
- Clapham, J. (1944) The Bank of England, p. 246-247
- Clapham, p. 163
- Tyler Goodspeed: Legislating Instability: Adam Smith, Free Banking, and the Financial Crisis of 1772, p. 4
- Koudijs & Voth, p. 25
- Sutherland, Lucy (1 January 1984). Politics & Finance in the Eighteenth Century. Bloomsbury Academic. p. 446. ISBN 9780907628460. Retrieved 23 March 2013.
Neal, James, Fordyce and Down.
- The Gentleman's Magazine and Historical Chronicle (London: June 1772) MDCCLXXII, pages 293
- David Bholat (2009) THINKING ABOUT THE CRISIS How Would Adam Smith Fix the Financial Crisis?
- Dillen, J.G. van (1970) Van Rijkdom en Regenten, p. 610
- "Börsenwissen für Einsteiger und Fortgeschrittene".
- A History of Banking in All the Leading Nations, p. 190
- https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/museum/slavery-and-the-bank-large-print-guide.pdf
- Kerr, Andrew William (1908). History of Banking in Scotland (2nd ed.). London: A. & C. Black. pp. 110–111.
- Smith (1976), vol. 2, p. 264-65
- Hoonhout, Bram (2013) The crisis of the subprime plantation mortgages in the Dutch West Indies, 1750-1775, p. 97
- Tyler Goodspeed: Legislating Instability: Adam Smith, Free Banking, and the Financial Crisis of 1772, p. 10
- Hoonhout, Bram (2013) The crisis of the subprime plantation mortgages in the Dutch West Indies, 1750-1775, p. 99
- J.P. van der Voort (1973) DE WESTINDISCHE PLANTAGES van 1720 tot 1795, p. 154
- Clapham, p. 248
- The Descent of Central Banks (1400–1815) by William Roberds and François R. Velde (2014)
- Wilson, C. Anglo-Dutch Commerce and Finance in the 18th Century (1966) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, p. 176
- Van Dillen, p. 613
- The 1772–73 British Credit Crisis by Paul Kosmetatos
- The International Lender of Last Resort- An Historical Perspective by Joanna Rudd
- Sautijn Kluit, W.P. (1865) De Amsterdamsche Beurs in 1763 en 1773, p. 96-97
- Clapham, J. (1944) The Bank of England, p. 248
- Hans Chr. Johansen (1966) J. G. Büsch's economic theory and his influence on the Danish economic and social debate, Scandinavian Economic History Review, 14:1, 18-38, DOI: 10.1080/03585522.1966.10407646 https://doi.org/10.1080/03585522.1966.10407646
- The Origins and Nature of Scandinavian Central Banking by Steffen Elkiær Andersen, p. 57-58
- The First Modern Economy: Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch ...by Jan de Vries, Ad van der Woude, p.140
- At Spes non Fracta: Hope & Co. 1770–1815 by M.G. Buist, p. 22
- J.G. van Dillen (1973), p. 609
- Sautijn Kluit, W.P. (1865) De Amsterdamsche Beurs in 1763 en 1773, p. 72
- https://www.americanheritage.com/1772two-hundred-and-twenty-five-years-ago
- L. Sutherland 1952, pp. 249-251
- Clapham, J. (1944) The Bank of England, p. 250
- https://dinarrecaps.com/our-blog/a-different-way-to-think-about-the-evergrande-collapse
- Samuel Flagg Bernis, "Jay’s Treaty, A Study in Commerce and Diplomacy" (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1923). Print. page 103.
- Lucy S. Sutherland, "Sir George Colebrooke’s World Corner in Alum, 1771-73," Economic History, III (Feb. 1936). page 248-69.
- "Tea and Antipathy" American Heritage
References
- Sheridan, Richard B. “The British Credit Crisis of 1772 and The American Colonies.” The Journal of Economic History, vol. 20, no. 2, 1960, pp. 161–86, http://www.jstor.org/stable/2114853. Accessed 9 Apr. 2022.
- Kynaston, David (2017). Till Time's Last Sand: A History of the Bank of England, 1694–2013. New York: Bloomsbury. pp. 51–52. ISBN 978-1408868560.